Bundling Information Goods:
Pricing, Profits and Efficiency

Yannis Bakos* and Erik Brynjolfsson**

Table of Contents

Return to Sections 1 - 7 and References

Appendix 1: Proofs of Propositions

Appendix 2: A mechanism for recovering information about the valuations of individual goods


Appendix 1: Proofs of Propositions

Proposition 1

Consider a bundle of zero marginal cost goods, each with i.i.d. valuations with mean and standard deviation . Let be the probability density function for a consumer's valuation for this bundle, and letand be the mean and standard deviation for the valuation of the bundle adjusted for n; i.e., and. Denote by , the optimal mean price for the bundle (adjusted for n) and the corresponding quantity (), and let be the resulting profits per good . Let and . We show that and . (If these limits do not exist, the same reasoning can be applied to convergent subsequences of and , as is bounded, and so is because of the finite variance assumption.)

If P>m, there exists some e>0 such that for all large enough n, . By the weak law of large numbers, , where or . Thus if P>m, , and since is bounded, , which contradicts the optimality of and .

If P<m, there exists some e>0 such that for all large enough n, . Let , and the corresponding quantity. The weak law of large numbers implies that , and . Since for large enough n, , it follows that , which again contradicts the optimality of and . Thus .

If , let and , so that . Since converges to Q and , there exists some such that for all . Choose such that , which is satisfied for , and let be the quantity sold at price . By the weak law of large numbers, , and thus there exists some such that for all . Finally, since converges to m as shown above, there exists some such that for . Let . Then for , setting a price yields corresponding sales and revenues . Since e was chosen so that , we get , contradicting the optimality of and .

Proposition 2

Using the same notation as in Proposition 1, we assume that, for all integer and all , .

This assumption implies that the quantity of the bundle of goods sold at price per good will increase compared to the bundle of goods, i.e., . This guarantees that . Adding the th good to the bundle is desirable for the seller, because a bundle of goods is more profitable than a bundle of goods plus a single good sold separately, since .

Assumption A5 also implies that (otherwise would not be optimal), allowing the reasoning above to be applied inductively, which proves the proposition for all .

Proposition 3

If the marginal cost is higher than the mean valuation, it is easily seen that bundling is unprofitable at the limit as . Separate sales are still profitable as long as some consumers' valuations are higher than the marginal cost.

Proposition 4

Without bundling, the seller faces a downward sloping demand function for each individual good, resulting in a monopolistic equilibrium price of and corresponding profit of . Bundling allows the seller to capture the entire consumer valuations, thus resulting in average profit . Bundling becomes unattractive when , or . As , this condition is met when .

Proposition 5

Given a consumer's type w, valuations are i.i.d. for all goods and uniformly distributed in , i.e., , where .

The probability that a consumer of type w will value any particular good at x is for . Thus the sum of valuations for consumers with valuation at level x equals , and consequently the unbundled demand at price p is

and thus .

As n increases, the mean valuation for a bundle of n goods by a consumer of type converges stochastically to . Thus at a price per good for the bundle , the seller will sell to a fraction of the consumers; i.e., those with type . The resulting demand curve is , and thus the profit-maximizing bundle price is per good, and the corresponding average profits are and the deadweight loss is . If third-degree price discrimination is feasible, however, the seller will set , resulting in profits of , no deadweight loss, and full extraction of consumer surplus.

Proposition 6

If a consumer of type with preferred consumption level for the discriminating feature chooses a lower consumption level , which is the preferred level for type , the resulting utility loss is . That consumer values the bundle at , and it can be shown that the optimal price schedule is linear: if a consumer's consumption level for the discriminating feature implies type w, the seller charges that consumer price , which results in a truth-telling equilibrium in which each consumer selects the level d implied by his or her type w.

The resulting demand function is , with sales at price . The seller realizes profit , where w* characterizes the marginal consumer that will purchase the bundle. This profit can be calculated to be , and solving yields . Substituting dW for w in the price schedule above yields the result in the Proposition.

Thus, unless , the optimal pricing strategy for the bundle involves taking advantage of the feature d to price-discriminate. If , then the seller is able to achieve third-degree price discrimination, charging each consumer their reservation value for the bundle, and extracting the entire consumer surplus, resulting in higher profits and no deadweight loss.

Appendix 2: A mechanism for recovering information about the valuations of individual goods

The proposed mechanism works as follows:

1. For each good i, expose a random subsample of si potential consumers to prices that make them reveal their demand for this good. These consumers will not have access to good i, which is normally in the bundle, unless they pay an additional price, pi.

2. Extrapolate the information from the subsamples to the rest of the population. If these si consumers are sufficiently representative, then their choices will provide a (noisy) signal of what the demand of the whole population, S, would have been for good i.

This mechanism requires preventing arbitrage among consumers, a condition that can be enforced through technical means, such as public key encryption and authentication; legal means, such as copyrights and patents; social sanctions, such as norms against piracy; or combinations of the three. This mechanism will lead to a deadweight loss for those si consumers who are included in the sample, since some of them may choose to forgo consumption of the good. If si = S, then the mechanism provides exactly the same information as the conventional price system at exactly the same cost. However, it is likely that for most purposes a sufficiently accurate estimate of demand can be calculated for si << S, because of the rapidly declining informativeness (O()) of additional draws from the sample, as shown in Figure 6.

While the conventional price system provides only a binary signal of whether a given consumer's valuation is greater than or less than the market price, by offering different prices to different consumers one could estimate the shape of the entire demand curve, rather than just the portion near the market price. It may be too costly to experiment with prices far from the equilibrium price if all consumers must be offered the same price (Gal-Or, 1987), but if only a few consumers face off-equilibrium prices, then the costs can be kept manageable. Moreover, the shape of demand far from the equilibrium price is an important determinant of the total social surplus created by a good, and therefore the optimal investment policy regarding which types of goods should be created. For these reasons, our mechanism is likely to provide information about consumers' demand at a significantly lower social cost than the conventional price system, and it will never do worse.


Figure 6: Declining marginal benefits of larger samples

This statistical mechanism resembles the way investment decisions about certain information goods are actually made. For instance, information about consumers' valuations of individual television programs is rarely obtained by forcing them to pay for particular programs. Instead, television content producers provide a bundle of the goods for free (broadcast TV) or for a fixed price (cable or direct satellite TV) and rely on statistical sampling by firms like Nielsen and Arbitron to estimate audience size and quality. Advertising rates are based on these estimates, and indirectly determine which types of new television content will be produced. As discussed in section 6.4, this mechanism also resembles how royalties are apportioned to composers and songwriters from the revenues paid by nightclubs, restaurants, and other venues.

Finally, test-marketing of new products using focus groups also has similarities with the mechanism we describe. In fact, any signal that is reliably correlated with consumers' expected valuation for a good can serve as a substitute for the information provided by the conventional price system. These indicators could include prices from related product markets or populations, time spent visiting a site on the World Wide Web, the number of keystrokes made while in a particular application, survey answers on what users say they like, the expert opinion of product specialists, or ratings generated by collaborative filtering mechanisms (see, e.g., Avery, Resnick & Zeckhauser, 1995; Urban, Weinberg & Hauser, 1996).