Correspondence to:
Erik Brynjolfsson
MIT room E53-313
Cambridge, MA 02139
Keywords: Organizational design, information systems,
economics
This paper, and the special issue, address relationships between information systems and changes in the organization of modern enterprise, both within and across firms. The emerging organizational paradigm involves complementary changes in multiple dimensions. The revolution in information systems merits special attention as both cause and effect of the organizational transformation. This can be illustrated by considering two key variables: the location of information and the location of decision rights in organizations. Depending on the costs of information transmission and processing, either the "MIS solution" of transferring information, or the "organizational redesign solution" of moving decision rights, can be an effective approach toward achieving the necessary collocation of information and decision rights. When information systems change radically, one cannot expect the optimal organizational structure to be unaffected. Considering the interplay among information, incentives and decision rights in a unified fashion leads to new insights and a better organizational planning. The papers in the special issue address different facets of this interaction. Despite significant progress, our understanding of the economic role of information systems in organizations remains in its infancy. We conclude that successful design of modern enterprise will require further narrowing of the historic gap between research in information systems and research in economics.
The organization of work is in the midst of transformation. In many industries, mass production by large, vertically-integrated, hierarchically-organized firms is giving way to more flexible forms of both internal organization and industrial structure. Work is increasingly accomplished through networks of smaller, more focused enterprises. The resulting structure of loosely coupled sub-organizations blurs the boundaries of both firms and industries.
A canonical case in point is the computer industry. In the past, the industry was dominated by large, vertically-integrated firms such as IBM and Digital Equipment which created products and services throughout the value chain -- from the microprocessor level all the way up to the provision of solutions. The vertical structure is now being replaced by a series of layers, each of which is, in effect, a separate industry. Value is generated by ever-changing coalitions, where each member of a coalition specializes in its area of core competence and leverages it through the use of tactical or strategic partnerships. Internally, team structures are replacing the traditional hierarchical form, and the Silicon Valley model of internal organization is emerging as a clear winner.3 Internal incentives are increasingly based on performance, and this further blurs the differences between inter- and intra-firm contracts. In sum, modern enterprise is undergoing major restructuring.
In this short paper we briefly discuss the newly emerging organizational
paradigms and their relationship to the prevailing trends in information
technology (IT). We argue that IT is an important driver of this
transformation. Finally, we place the studies selected for this
special issue of the Journal of Organizational Computing
within this context.
At the turn of the century, Frederick Taylor sought to put the
nascent wisdom for successful business organization on a scientific
basis. His work guided a generation of managers towards success
in meshing their organizations with the technologies, markets,
labor and general environment of the era. By the 1920s, Henry
Ford had applied the Taylorist approach with a vengeance and soon
dominated the automobile market, driving dozens of competitors
under. Ironically, these same principles are almost diametrically
opposed to the prevailing wisdom of the 1990s. For example, consider
the following guideline from The Science of Management [1]
It is necessary in any activity to have a complete knowledge of what is to be done and to prepare instructions... the laborer has only to follow instructions. He need not stop to think.
The current emphasis on "empowerment", "learning organizations", and even "thriving on chaos" stands in sharp contrast to Meyers' advice (cf. [2] , [3] ). Similar contrast can be found with many, if not most, of the other principles that lead to success even as late as the 1960s. Consider, for example, the growing calls for downsizing (vs. economies of scale), focus (vs. conglomerates), total quality (vs. cost leadership), project teams (vs. functional departments), supplier partnerships (vs. maximizing bargaining power), networked organization (vs. clear firm boundaries); performance-based pay (vs. fixed pay), and local autonomy (vs. rigid hierarchy).
Milgrom and Roberts [4] make the point that the different characteristics of modern manufacturing, an important example of the emerging organizational paradigm, are often highly complementary. This complementarity, coupled with the natural tendency to change organizational attributes one at a time, makes the transition from one paradigm to another particularly difficult. Strong complementarity implies that in order to be successful, change must be implemented simultaneously along a number of related dimensions. Organizations that adopt only one or two key components of the new organizational paradigm may fail simply by virtue of this complementarity. For instance, Jaikumar's [5] study of 95 US and Japanese companies found that the majority of US companies had failed to achieve productivity increases despite switching to flexible manufacturing technology. The reason was that they had preserved dozens of manufacturing practices such as long production runs and high work-in-process inventory levels, which complemented the old technology but kept the new technology from fulfilling its potential. Thus, the transition from the old structure to the new one is overwhelmingly complex. The switch would be easier if we apply design guided by theory instead of piecemeal evolution.
There are many possible explanations for the change in the prevailing wisdom regarding organizational design. For instance, it is common to justify calls for radical change with reference to heightened competitive pressures: although firms that applied the old principles were among the most successful competitors of their day, presumably the nature of competition has changed in some way. Others suggest that consumer tastes have changed, making customized items more appealing than they once were. While historians would argue that the taste for mass marketed items was itself something that had to be developed in the early days of mass production, increased wealth or social stratification may make this more difficult today. It can also be argued that some of the new principles were as applicable fifty years ago as they are today, but that they simply had not yet been discovered.
Although the enablers of the current organizational transformation
are undoubtedly numerous and far from mutually independent, we
would like to single one out for special attention: the rise in
IT. Brynjolfsson [6, p.6] argues that IT is an appropriate
candidate for explaining these changes for three reasons:
First, compared to other explanations, the advances in information technology have a particularly reasonable claim to being both novel and exogenous. Many of the fundamental technological breakthroughs that enable today's vast information infrastructure were made less than a generation ago and were driven more by progress in physics and engineering than business demand. Second, the growth in information technology investment is of a large enough magnitude to be economically significant ... the result has been what is commonly referred to as the "information explosion"... Third, there is a sound basis for expecting an association between the costs of technologies that manage information and the organization of economic activity. The firm and the market have each been frequently modeled as primarily information processing institutions (see Galbraith [7] and Hayek [8] , respectively).
Miller [9] foresaw the key features of the new paradigm as a
natural outcome of the information era and the associated "economy
of choice":
The new technologies will allow managers to handle more functions and widen their span of control. Fewer levels of management hierarchy will be required, enabling companies to flatten the pyramid of today's management structure. The new information technologies allow decentralization of decision-making without loss of management awareness; thus employees at all levels can be encouraged to be more creative and intrapreneurial. The key responsibility of the CEO will be leadership; to capture the light or energies of the organization -- like a lens -- and focus them on the key strategic objectives.
The new organizational paradigm is indeed intertwined with the
structure of an organization's information systems. Under the
old paradigm, the firm was governed by a relatively rigid functional
structure. This separation into distinct and well-defined organizational
units economizes on the information and communications requirements
across functional units and reduces cost and complexity. There
is a tradeoff, however: the old structure is less flexible, less
responsive and ultimately results in lower quality. In our view,
the growing use of IT and the trend towards networking and client-server
computing are both a cause and an effect of the organizational
transition. Lowering the costs of horizontal communications,
facilitating teamwork, enabling flexible manufacturing and providing
information support for time management and quality control are
key enablers on the supply side. It is equally clear that the
new organizational paradigm demands new information systems: nothing
can be more devastating for cross-functional teamwork than a rigid
information system that inhibits cross-functional information
flows. We can unify these perspectives by noting that the structure
of the organization's information system is a key element of
organizational
transformation. Changes in IT change the nature of organizations
just as changes in organizational structure drive the development
of new technologies.
Jensen and Meckling [10] provide a useful framework for studying the complementarities between information systems, incentive structures and decision rights in organizations. In their framework, the structure of an organization is specified by three key elements: (i) The allocation of decision rights (i.e., who is responsible for what actions/decisions); (ii) the incentive system, which defines how decision makers are to be rewarded (or penalized) for the decisions they make; and (iii) a monitoring and measurement scheme used to evaluate these actions and their outcomes.
According to Jensen and Meckling, informational variables are key to the structure of organizations because the quality of decisions is determined by the quality of information available to the decision maker. The co-location of information and decision rights enables the decision maker to make optimal decisions. The implementation of this co-location depends on the nature of the pertinent information. Jensen and Meckling distinguish between "specific knowledge" which is localized, difficult to represent and transfer, and depends on idiosyncratic circumstances, and "general knowledge" which can be easily summarized, communicated and shared by decision makers.
Now, there are two ways to bring information and decision rights
together: (i) "The MIS solution": transfer the
information required for the decision to the decision maker, using
the organization's (possibly non-automated) information systems;
or (ii) "the organizational redesign solution":
redesign the organizational structure so that the decision making
authority is where the pertinent information is. By definition,
general knowledge which is useful for a decision calls for the
"MIS solution" because it can be transferred at low
cost. In contrast, when specific knowledge plays a key role in
a decision, the best solution calls for restructuring decision
rights so as to provide the decision authority to the one who
possesses or has access to the pertinent information (since the
transfer of specific knowledge is too costly).4
Jensen and Meckling thus represent the structure of organizations as an efficient response to the structure of their information costs. But then, a change in information costs must induce a change in organizational structure. In particular, IT has changed the costs of processing and transferring certain types of information (e.g. quantitative data), but has done little for other types (e.g. implicit knowledge or skills). IT changes the structure of organizations by facilitating certain information flows as well as by turning knowledge that used to be specific into general knowledge. By developing a taxonomy of information types and identifying the differential impacts of new technologies on their transferability and importance, we can take a significant step towards applying the simple insight that information and authority should be co-located [11] .
Intra-organizational networks and workgroup computing facilities reduce the information costs of teamwork and hence make it a more efficient solution to the organizational design problem. Client-server computing technology lowers cross-functional (as well as geographic) barriers. IT (when applied properly) streamlines the types of information that used to be the raison d'etre of middle management -- quantitative control information -- and turns it into general knowledge that can be readily transmitted to, and processed by, people other than those who originally gathered the data. A reduction in the number of management layers and the thinning out of middle management ranks is the predictable result.
Similar considerations apply to enterprises that cross firm boundaries. As a simple example, consider the organization of trading activities [12, 13, 14] . Traditionally, trading took place on the floor of an exchange, which was the locus of numerous pieces of specific knowledge, ranging from the hand signals indicating bids and offers to buy and sell a security to traders' facial expressions and the "atmosphere" on the floor of the exchange. Under that structure, much of the information pertinent to trading is specific and localized to the floor. Thus, when an investor instructs her broker to sell 1,000 shares of a given stock, the broker transmits the order to the floor of the exchange and only the floor broker attempts to provide "best execution". The decision rights (here, for the trading decisions) are naturally delegated to the decision maker who has the pertinent specific knowledge, and since that knowledge resides on the floor of the exchange, the floor broker is best suited to have the decision rights. Technology, and in particular "screen-based" systems, turns much of the specific knowledge on the floor (i.e., bids and offers) into general knowledge. This shifts decision rights up from the floor to the brokers' screens. The inevitable result is the decline of the trading floor and the increased importance of brokers' trading rooms. The demise of the trading floor in exchanges that turned to screen-based trading (such as London and Paris) is a natural outcome of the shift in the locus of knowledge. More generally, markets -- in particular, electronic markets --transform specific knowledge into general knowledge [15] .
Ironically, even as IT has sped up many links of the information processing chain and vastly increased the amount of information available to any one decision-maker, it has also led to the phenomenon of "information overload". This can perhaps best be understood by a generalization of the Jensen and Meckling framework to include finite human information processing capacity. As more information moves from the "specific" category to the "general" category, the limiting factor becomes not what information is available but rather a matter of finding the human information processing capacity needed to attend to and process the information. Computers appear to have exacerbated the surfeit of information relative to processing capacity, perhaps because the greatest advances have occurred in the processing and storage of structured data, which is generally a complement, not a substitute, for human information processing. As computer and communications components increase their speed, the human bottleneck in the information processing chain becomes ever more apparent.
Information overload, when interpreted in light of this framework, can provide an explanation for the increased autonomy and pay-for-performance that characterize a number of descriptions of the "new managerial work" (cf. [6] ). Economizing on information costs means that more decision rights are delegated to line managers who possess the idiosyncratic, specific knowledge necessary to accomplish their tasks. Shifting responsibility from the overburdened top of the hierarchy to line personnel not only reduces the information processing load at the top of the hierarchy, but also cuts down unnecessary communications up and down the hierarchy. This blurs the traditional distinction between "conceptualization" and "execution" and broadens the scope of decision rights delegated to lower level managers. By the Jensen-Meckling [10] framework, any such shift in decision authority (and in the associated routing of information) must also be accompanied by a change in the structure of incentives. Disseminating information more broadly is ever easier with IT, allowing line workers to take into account information that goes well beyond the formerly-narrow definitions of their job.
Meanwhile, providing the right incentives for the newly "empowered" work force is an equally crucial element of the current reorganization of work. Agency theory predicts that performance-based "pay" is necessary when decision rights are decentralized (otherwise, the agents may be induced to act in ways that are inconsistent with overall organizational goals). It therefore follows that incentive-based compensation is appropriate for better-informed workers [16].5 Thus, the confluence of better-informed workers, an empowered workforce and more incentive-based pay is consistent with our thesis that IT is a key driver of the new organizational paradigm.
Furthermore, the theory of incomplete contracts suggests that
the analysis can be extended to include interorganizational changes
such as increased reliance on outsourcing and "networks"
of other firms for key components [17] . Here again the shift
can be explained in incentive terms: one ultimate incentive is
ownership, so entrepreneurs are likely to be more innovative and
aggressive than the same individuals working as "division"
managers. Both within and across organizations, then, changes
in information systems are accompanied by changes in incentives
and in the organization of work.
The papers in this special issue attest to the role of information systems in the structure of modern enterprise and the blurring of the differences between inter- and intra-firm transactions. Starting from the firm's level, Barron's paper studies how a firm determines its internal organization and how IT affects this determination. Barron considers a traditional firm, with well-defined boundaries that are endogenously determined by considering flexibility and scope of control. Ching, Holsapple and Whinston broaden the scope of the enterprise to the "network organization" -- a construct obtained by tying together a number of firms that cooperate through a well-defined communication mechanism. Specifically, they use a bidding protocol to manage the relationship between suppliers and producers. Beath and Ang examine another form of inter-firm cooperation, the relational contract, in the context of software-development outsourcing. They show how relational contracts embody a relationship that can be characterized as a network consisting of two organizations. Whang studies a more subtle form of networking -- information sharing between buyers and suppliers. Bakos and Brynjolfsson examine the impact of incentives and information costs on the nature of buyer-supplier relationships. They show that committing to a partnership with a small number of suppliers can be an optimal strategy for a buyer because it will maximize the suppliers' incentives for non-contractible investments such as information sharing, innovation or quality.
The papers thus present a spectrum ranging from a study of the boundaries of the traditional firm through different forms of networking to explicit buyer-supplier relationships. A common theme is the organization of work so as to reduce overall information costs not only within an organization but across them as well. The surviving enterprise is often (though not always) the one that attempts to reduce information costs while capitalizing on the comparative advantage of the participating organizations. This calls for "opportunistic cooperation" that benefits the members of the network for as long as they cooperate. IT reduces the costs of such cooperation by facilitating communication and increasing the flexibility of the participating organizations. Using the Jensen-Meckling terminology, different network participants can make more effective use of their specific knowledge when the costs of transferring and processing general knowledge are reduced. Further, technology enables the development of markets that, by their very nature, transform specific knowledge into general knowledge. Thus, the bidding and communications protocols proposed by Ching, Holsapple and Whinston in their paper "Modeling Network Organizations" effectively transform the specific knowledge inherent in the production technology of the competing suppliers into general knowledge that encompasses not only prices but also their reputations. From this perspective, IT is key to the development of network organizations.
In his paper "Impacts of Information Technology on Organizational Size and Shape: Control and Flexibility Effects", Barron builds a stylized quantitative model to study the impact of IT on the structure of organizations. Examining flexibility and scope of control, he identifies sixteen different cases with different patterns of the actual causality between IT and firm structure. Barron shows that simplistic statements regarding the impact of IT are not as straightforward as one might imagine due to the interaction of size, scope and flexibility. His results suggest that the impact of IT is rather complex, and that further specification is necessary prior to making predictions on the impact of IT on organizational size or shape.
"Hierarchical Elements in Software Contracts" by Beath and Ang focuses on the contractual structure of outsourced software development. This is an interesting example of the new organizational paradigm because of the key role of information systems in any organization. Effective software development hinges on cooperation, communication and joint management which are at the heart of the new organizational paradigm. Beath and Ang examine the mechanisms used to govern outsourcing projects as specified in their outsourcing contracts. They suggest that the relational contract, which converts an arms-length transaction into a joint project with governance and resolution procedures that resemble those used by firms internally, is an effective way to accomplish this. Thus, while Ching, Holsapple and Whinston view bidding and explicit reputation formation as the alphabet of the network organization, Beath and Ang view actual contract clauses as the key linguistic constructs. The paper shows how the structure of the contract is driven by the attributes of the project as well as those of the parties to the transaction.
In "Analysis of Economic Incentives for Inter-Organizational Information Sharing", Whang addresses the question of information sharing in non-cooperative buyer-supplier settings. Whang studies this question for two different models. He first shows that due to adverse incentives, suppliers will not be willing to share information regarding their costs. The situation is different when the information to be conveyed is regarding the expected delay or lead time. Whang shows that suppliers are better off disclosing lead-time information to buyers (when the demand curve for their product is convex). This result is consistent with our general thesis, whereas the former one introduces a note of caution: adverse incentives pose limits to the scope of information sharing among network organizations.
In "From Vendors to Partners: Information Technology and Incomplete Contracts in Buyer-Supplier Relationships", Bakos and Brynjolfsson start with the assumption that, in many cases, complete information exchange between two firms will be infeasible, so any contract between them will be "incomplete" in the sense that some contingencies will remain unspecified. They then explore how the interplay of IT and organizational structure can affect the role of non-contractible investments, such as innovation, quality and the exchange of information. For example, Bakos and Brynjolfsson show that when fewer suppliers are employed, they collectively capture a larger share of the benefits of the relationship, and this will increase their incentives to make non-contractible investments. As a result, even when search costs are very low, it may be desirable for the buyer to limit the number of employed suppliers, leading to a partnership-type of relationship, rather than aggressively bargaining for all the benefits by threatening to switch among numerous alternative suppliers. Like Whang, they show that the incentive effects of the applications of IT must be explicitly considered in any model of their effect on inter-organizational cooperation.
In this paper, we have stressed the joint determination of the location of information and decision rights. The default mechanism used to achieve this co-location depends on one's point of reference. Information Systems researchers are likely to take the locus of decision authority for granted. They will typically focus their attention on devising schemes that will efficiently organize, retrieve, sort, filter, transmit and display information for designated decision makers. In contrast, the economist is likely to focus on the allocation of decision rights and the concomitant effect on incentives.6 As we discussed in Section 2, transferring information and transferring decision authority are two sides of the same question. Because economics and information systems research evolved to address different problems, this complementarity long went unnoticed.
Each of the papers in the special issue addresses a different aspect of the interplay among information, incentives and the structure of economic enterprise. In every case, insights resulted when both information and incentives were explicitly considered. Each paper contributes an additional piece to an emerging mosaic that describes not only the features of the new organization, but also gives some insight into their theoretical underpinnings.
The papers in this special issue also highlight the incomplete
state of knowledge in the subject area and the dearth of empirical
guidance to the formulation and testing of theoretical research.
We started this paper with a discussion of the computer industry
as the canonical example of the new paradigm as exercised in Silicon
Valley, and continued by arguing that its products actually fuel
the shift to this paradigm. It is only appropriate to close the
loop by examining the dictum of that paradigm as it applies to
the inner workings of firms in the computer industry. A major
effort along these lines in being undertaken by one of the authors
and his colleagues in Stanford University's Computer Industry
Project.
Understanding these changes so that they can be harnessed for productive ends remains a central challenge for the next decade of research. The rapid progress in designing computers and communications systems contrasts starkly with the uncertainty clouding organizational design. Yet, new ways of organizing will be necessary before the potential of IT can be realized.
Furthermore, because the new organizational paradigms involve numerous complementarities, the trial-and-error methods which were important in the rise of the organizational forms of the past century, such as large hierarchies and mass markets, may be unsuited for making the next transition. Understanding and implementing one aspect of a new organizational structure without regard to its interaction with other aspects can leave the make the organization worse off than if no modifications at all were made. Design, rather than evolution, is called for when significant changes must be made along multiple dimensions simultaneously.
Successful organizational design, in turn, requires that we understand
the flow of information among humans and their agents every bit
as well as we understand the flow of electrons in chips and wires.
Perhaps, then, the revolution in information processing capabilities
not only calls for a change in business organization, but also
a re-evaluation of the historic separation between Information
Systems and Economics.
[1] Meyers, G. The Science of Management. In C. B. Thompson (Eds.), Scientific Management Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1914.
[2] Kanter, R. M. "The New Managerial Work." Harvard Business Review, Nov-Dec, 1989, pp. 85-92.
[3] Peters, T. Thriving on Chaos, Handbook for a Management Revolution. New York: Knopf, 1988.
[4] Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. "The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technology, Strategy, and Organization." American Economic Review, Vol. 80, No. 3, 1990.
[5] Jaikumar, R. "Post-Industrial Manufacturing." Harvard Business Review, November-December, 1986, pp. 69-76.
[6] Brynjolfsson, E. Information Technology and the 'New Managerial Work'. Working Paper # 3563-93. MIT, 1990.
[7] Galbraith, J. Organizational Design. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 1977.
[8] Hayek, F. A. "The Use of Knowledge in Society." American Economic Review, Vol. 35, No. 4, 1945.
[9] Miller, W. F. The Economy of Choice. In Strategy, Technology and American Industry HBS Press, 1987.
[10] Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. Knowledge, Control and Organizational Structure Parts I and II. In Lars, Werin and Hijkander (Eds.), Contract Economics (pp.251-274). Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1992.
[11] Mendelson, H. On Centralization and Decentralization. Stanford, forthcoming, 1993.
[12] Amihud, Y. and Mendelson, H. An Integrated Computerized Trading System. In Market Making and the Changing Structure of the Securities Industry (pp. 217-235). Lexington Heath, 1985.
[13] Amihud, Y. and Mendelson, H. (1989). The Effects of Computer-Based Trading on Volatility and Liquidity. In H. C. Lucas Jr. and R. A. Schwartz (Eds.), The Challenge of Information Technology for the Securities Markets. (pp. 59-85). Dow Jones-Irwin.
[14] Amihud, Y. and Mendelson, H. "Liquidity, Volatility and Exchange Automation." Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance, Vol. 3, Fall, 1988, pp. 369-395.
[15] Malone, T. W., Yates, J. and Benjamin, R. I. "Electronic Markets and Electronic Hierarchies." Communications of the ACM, Vol. 30, No. 6, 1987, pp. 484-497.
[16] Baker, G. P. "Incentive Contracts and Performance Measurement." Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, No. 3, June, 1992.
[17] Brynjolfsson, E. "An Incomplete Contracts Theory of
Information, Technology, and Organization." Management
Science, forthcoming, 1993.